Skip to content

Why is there no economic theory of organizational design?

An article on the real-world practice of organizational design in the context of academic economic theory.

Published by Rupert Morrison 

Where is the economic theory of organization design?

Economists have puzzled over how to describe organizations for centuries. The 20th century theory of the firm originally had it that the firm was simply an optimization device. It exploited opportunities by adding more capital and more labor until marginal costs outweighed marginal revenues. Then the firm became a way of economizing on transactions costs that otherwise exist in markets [Coase, 1937[1]] and a device for ‘resolving conflicts of interest’ [Williamson, 1981[2]]. More recently, evolutionary and behavioral economists have talked about organizations’ routines and have measured their adaptability. [Hodgson & Knudsen, 2010[3], Herman 2013[4]]

I suspect that the descriptions of the firm have been hampered by (1) what it is possible to measure and (2) what it is possible to contract for in the firm.

Conventional MI and accounting does not express all the elements of the firm. Intellectual property, brand, reputation are only infrequently and imprecisely measured; ‘vision’, ‘mission’, ‘values’, ‘strategy’ never make it into company accounts.

Legal contracts similarly do not express all the elements of the firm. They rarely contract for competencies, capabilities and behaviors. Instead, contracts focus on assets that can be identified and transacted.

Because of this conceptual boundary, economic models find it hard to cope with the concepts such as ‘processes,’ ‘activities’ or ‘roles’. Yet when we design an organization, we’re seeking to address important elements such as: processes, competencies, capabilities, behaviors, roles, accountabilities, decision making rights, people, teams and structures. These are things that management theory often describes, yet economic (and accounting) theory does not describe. Why? It’s the limitation of concepts and measurability.

As Lord Kelvin said:

when you can measure what you are speaking about, and express it in numbers, you know something about it; but when you cannot express it in numbers, your knowledge is of a meagre and unsatisfactory kind; …you have scarcely, in your thoughts, advanced to the stage of science…” [5][

Part of the problem has been what people have been trying to measure. It’s difficult for example to isolate and define capabilities. Part of the problem has been how to keep the data still enough for long enough to measure it. The people themselves keep developing their skills, their environment changes and their roles within the organization keep changing. So what do we measure? The people? Their context? Their role? The instability of the data presents a simple but fundamental problem – anything that’s so disconnected, fragmented and hard to collect can hardly be measured and therefore can’t be included in contracts, annual accounts or board reports.

Think about a simple skill. How good are people with customers? Some are excellent. They engage, they listen to the other person and they tell it how it is. Others try hard but just don’t get it right. How valuable would it be to organizations to recruit people who are good with customers? How easily can the organization measure this and track its current capability?

References

[1] Coase, R., 1937, “The Nature of the Firm”, Economica 4 (16): 386–405

[2] Williamson, O.E., 1981 “The Economics of Organization: The Transaction Cost Approach”. The American Journal of Sociology 87 (3): 548–577

[3] Hodgson, G., & Knudsen, T., 2010, Darwin’s Conjecture: The Search for General Principles of Social and Economic Evolution, University of Chicago Press

[4] Herman, S., 2013: Stephen Herman’s doctoral thesis on Adaptability & Innovation routines, unpublished.

[5] Thomson, W, 1883: “Lecture on “Electrical Units of Measurement” (3 May 1883), published in Popular Lectures Vol. I, p. 73